Abstract
Bet-hedging—an evolutionary strategy that reduces fitness variance at the expense of lower mean fitness—is the primary explanation for most forms of biological adaptation to environmental unpredictability. However, most applications of bet-hedging theory to biological problems have largely made unrealistic demographic assumptions, such as non-overlapping generations and fixed population sizes. Consequently, the generality and applicability of bet-hedging theory to real world phenomena remains unclear. Here we use continuous-time, stochastic Lotka-Volterra models to relax overly restrictive demographic assumptions and explore a suite of biological adaptations to fluctuating environments. We discover a novel “rising-tide strategy” that—unlike the bet-hedging strategy—generates both a higher mean and variance in fitness. The positive fitness effects of the rising-tide strategy’s specialization to good years can overcome any negative effects of higher fitness variance in unpredictable environments. Moreover, we show not only that the rising-tide strategy will be selected for over a much broader range of environmental conditions than the bet-hedging strategy, but also under more realistic demographic circumstances. Ultimately, our model demonstrates that there are likely to be a wide range of ways that organisms respond to environmental unpredictability.
Temporal fluctuation of environmental conditions is a universal feature in nearly every ecosystem on earth1,2. In fluctuating environments, the intensity and direction of natural selection is likely to vary unpredictably over time3-5. Almost all known biological adaptations to environmental fluctuation—as diverse as seed production in annual plants6, phenotypic polymorphisms in bacteria7-9, and altruistic behavior in social animals10—are typically summarized by a single, simple mechanism: the evolutionary bet-hedging strategy1,11,12. There are two general types of bet-hedging: conservative bet-hedging describes a consistent but low risk strategy or phenotypic investment, whereas diversified bet-hedging depicts the case when organisms spread risk by investing in different strategies or phenotypes11,13. Both forms of bet-hedging result in the same fitness consequence: reduced variance in fitness at the expense of a lower mean fitness. In other words, under either bet-hedging scenario, natural selection can act optimally by minimizing fitness variance rather than by maximizing mean fitness.
Although the bet-hedging principle describes many forms of behavioral adaptation under fluctuating selection, it cannot explain all of the ways in which animals cope with environmental uncertainty. For example, studies exploring thermal niche evolution at different temporal scales of environmental fluctuation have demonstrated that although greater long-term environmental variation (e.g. seasonal variation in temperature) favors the evolution of thermal generalists, short-term variation (e.g. daily temperature variation) has an opposite effect by selecting for thermal specialists14,15. Essentially, these models hint at the theoretical possibility of a specialist strategy in which individuals have a higher mean fitness while also having higher variance in fitness. Such an adaptive strategy to environmental fluctuation—which differs fundamentally from a bet-hedging strategy—can also be derived using the approximation for geometric mean fitness, which increases with higher arithmetic mean fitness and lower fitness variance16-18. However, optimality models based on geometric mean fitness rely on the restrictive assumptions of non-overlapping generations and infinite population sizes, both of which do not apply to most eukaryotic species. Indeed, fluctuation in population size—which when environmentally-driven is analogous to a population going through a bottleneck in bad years and an expansion in good years19—can have substantial effects on the strength and direction of selection in populations of finite size20. The strength of natural selection, which can be represented by the opportunity for selection (defined as the variation of relative fitness21,22), is greater when populations decrease in size but lower when populations expand. However, the assumption of non-overlapping generations—which is typically used in most models of this sort (e.g. the grain-size model23)—creates a distinction between within-and among-generation selection, and only applies to a very limited number of real world organisms such as some microbes10,24. As a consequence, identifying general rules of biological adaptation to environmental fluctuation—particularly for species with overlapping generations and finite population sizes—remain elusive.
To achieve a more comprehensive understanding of biological adaptation to environmental fluctuation that applies to organisms without having to evoke restrictive demographic assumptions that are biologically unrealistic for most animal species, we use continuous-time, stochastic Lotka-Volterra models to examine the impact of differential selective forces with varying population sizes, different temporal scales of environmental fluctuation, and distinctive patterns of generational overlap. We use a competitive Lotka-Volterra model as our basic framework because this approach restricts population size through competition, rather than externally setting an absolute boundary on population size. In other words, population size is dynamically regulated by the fitness of each strategy, which is in turn affected by environmental conditions and population size itself. Moreover, Lotka-Volterra models can be used to explore the process of natural selection, as in Moran models that incorporate birth and death processes25, without the unrealistic assumption of a fixed population size26. Fundamentally, our model always allows for competition to reduce the number of surviving strategies, yet the direction of selection may not be the same at each moment because environmental conditions fluctuate (i.e. fluctuating selection).
We begin by employing the generalist-specialist trade-off concept15,27 to explore the selection dynamics of a generalist bet-hedging strategy that persists in both good and bad years and a specialist strategy that instead favors good years (hereafter referred to as the “rising-tide strategy”). Specifically, the specialist rising-tide strategy is defined as an evolutionary strategy that has relatively high fitness in good years so that its population size and relative frequency in the population increase, but relatively low fitness in bad years such that its population size and relative frequency decrease (Fig. 1). Thus, unlike the bet-hedging strategy, which can have higher mean fitness but lower variance in fitness, the rising-tide strategy can have both a higher mean fitness and a higher variance in fitness (Fig.1b). Importantly, just as the generalist and specialist strategies represent two ends of a continuum, the bet-hedging and rising-tide strategies should also be viewed as two ends of an adaptive continuum to fluctuating environments. In other words, the bet-hedging and rising-tide strategies are endpoints along a continuum of potential adaptations to environmental fluctuation that differ only in their relationships between fitness mean and variance.
For simplicity, we begin by presenting the discrete version of the bet-hedging and rising-tide strategies under two types of environmental conditions: good and bad years (in a later section, we present the continuous versions of the generalist bet-hedging and specialist rising-tide strategies, as well as how they both respond to different temporal scales of environmental fluctuation). The selection dynamics of the rising-tide, dNR/dt, and bet-hedging, dNB/dt, strategies in good years are: and where r stands for the intrinsic growth rate (i.e. birth minus death rate), N represents the population size of each strategy, α describes the intensity of competition between two strategies, and Kdenotes the carrying capacity. The capital subscripts R and B represent the parameters for the rising-tide strategy and the bet-hedging strategy, respectively. Similarly, the lower-case subscripts g and b represent good and bad years, respectively. For example, αBR,g indicates the intensity of competition between the bet-hedging and rising-tide strategies in good years. Similarly, the selection dynamics of each strategy in a bad year are: and
We begin by investigating the selection dynamics of the bet-hedging and rising-tide strategies using individual-based simulations, i.e. a stochastic continuous time model with random environmental settings, because this approach allows us to manipulate environmental stochasticity and track reproductive success at the individual level in order to calculate each strategy’s fixation probability and opportunity for selection (i.e. variance of relative fitness). We find that greater environmental variation can generate either the bet-hedging or the rising-tide strategy, but which end of the adaptive continuum is favored depends upon the frequency of good versus bad years (Fig. 1, see Supplementary Table 1 for parameter values). That is, the bet-hedging strategy has a higher fixation probability when bad years are more frequent than good years, whereas the rising-tide strategy is favored by selection when good years are more likely to occur than bad ones. When bad years are frequent, the risk aversion strategy of bet-hedging maximizes fitness by reducing variance rather than optimizing the mean, as has been shown previously1,11-13. However, when good years are more frequent than bad years, the positive impacts of a rising-tide strategy in the good years are able to sustain those individuals during the bad years (Fig. 1a-c). Importantly—and also consistent with previous theories—we find that the opportunity for selection rises when total population size declines (Fig. 1f-h) (results from the deterministic continuous time model with periodical environment setting are qualitatively similar; Supplementary Fig. 1). Therefore, the same magnitude of absolute fitness increase has a greater impact on the frequency of each phenotype in bad years than in good years. Thus, adaptation to bad years takes on a greater importance when bad years occur more frequently (and vice versa).
To further investigate how different temporal scales of environmental fluctuation—often referred to as the grain of the environmental variation; sensu12—influence the evolution of the bet-hedging and rising-tide strategies, we employ continuous versions of the generalist bet-hedging and specialist rising-tide strategies (Fig. 1a). Instead of assuming discrete environmental conditions (i.e. good versus bad years) as we did above, we now allow the environmental conditions E to vary continuously—just as temperature and rainfall do in nature—and influence the birth rate b(E), death rate d(E), and carrying capacity K(E) of each strategy (see Methods, eqns. 5 and 6). Thus, this is a stochastic continuous time model with random continuous environmental settings. The dynamics of the specialist rising-tide, dNR/dt, and generalist bet-hedging strategies, dNB/dt, in the stochastic Lotka-Volterra competitive model are: and
The capital subscripts R and B represent the parameters for rising-tide and bet-hedging strategy, respectively.
We find that long-term (e.g. annual) and short-term (e.g. daily) environmental fluctuations can have complex, but often counterintuitive, effects on adaptive evolutionary responses (Fig. 2, see Supplementary Table 2 for parameter values). When short-term environmental variation is relatively low, higher long-term variation selects for the bet-hedging strategy (Fig. 2c). However, the rising-tide strategy out-competes the bet-hedging strategy as short-term variation increases (Fig. 2d). When both short-and long-term environmental variation are relatively high, the bet-hedging strategy again becomes more dominant (Fig. 2e). Furthermore, when long-term environmental variation is relatively low, the rising-tide strategy is favored by selection under both low or high short-term environmental variation (Fig. 2i-k) because if long-term variation is relatively low, a rising-tide strategy, by definition, is more likely to specialize in a given mean environment (Fig. 2i). However, if long-term environmental variation is relatively high and if there is no, or only a small degree of, short-term environmental variation, by definition, a rising-tide specialist will not experience its optimal environmental conditions frequently (Fig. 2a and 2b). In other words, higher short-term variation can favor the evolution of specialization because a rising-tide specialist is likely to experience its optimal environmental conditions more frequently. This mechanism is similar to the one we described previously, namely that the specialist rising-tide strategy experiences more good than bad years and can therefore outcompete the generalist bethedging strategy, even when the variance in absolute fitness of the rising-tide strategy is higher than that of the bet-hedging strategy.
To more directly determine how our framework performs relative to more traditional approaches, we compare our continuous time, overlapping generations model with one that utilizes discrete population dynamics to approximate the commonly used but less realistic non-overlapping generations models (e.g.1,11,13,23) (Fig. 3, see eqns. 7 and 8 in Methods for more details). In most of these models, the temporal scale of environmental fluctuation is often classified as either (i) coarse grain, which describes among-generation variation in environmental conditions, or (ii) fine grain, which describes within-generation variation in environmental conditions12,23. In our comparison, we find that patterns of generation overlap are crucial for the evolution of the generalist-specialist continuum and the adoption of a bet-hedging versus a rising-tide strategy (Fig. 4, see Supplementary Table 2 for parameter values). In this stochastic discrete time model with a random continuous environmental setting, when long-term variation is high—which is similar to coarse grain variation in discrete-population dynamics models—the bet-hedging strategy dominates the rising-tide strategy in most of the parameter space (Fig. 4a-h). Nevertheless, higher short-term variation—which is equivalent to fine grain variation in our model—still favors the rising-tide strategy when long-term variation is relatively low (Fig. 4i).
The key features of nearly all previously-published non-overlapping generations models (e.g.1,11,13,23) are that the fitness consequences of environmental variation within a generation are additive within an organism’s lifetime, but multiplicative among generations. Thus, mathematically, the long-term growth rate of each strategy is determined by its geometric mean of fitness28-31. As a result, bet-hedging generalists occur more commonly under a non-overlapping generations scenario because a small absolute fitness in any generation will have a detrimental effect on the long-term growth rate of a strategy. Since our model allows for overlapping generations, birth and death events, and continuous changes in the strength of selection, the rising-tide strategy will be favored by natural selection under a wide range of environmental conditions as long as these specialists are able to encounter their optimal environment (i.e. good years) frequently enough so that they can sustain through adverse environmental conditions (i.e. bad years), even when they achieve lower fitness than under optimal conditions.
In summary, we have identified a novel form of behavioral adaptation to fluctuating environments: the rising-tide strategy. Although both the rising-tide and the bet-hedging strategies are possible when environmentally-driven fitness variation is high, the rising-tide strategy will be favored when mean fitness is higher and the bet-hedging strategy when mean fitness is lower. This difference in which strategy will be favored is determined by the grain of environmental variation, or the frequency of good and bad years within unpredictable environments. Previous theories have provided a heuristic understanding of adaptation to fluctuation environments by considering the mean and variance of fitness associated with the change of environmental conditions in species with non-overlapping generations and populations of fixed size. Our model further shows that under more biologically realistic scenarios involving species with overlapping generations and populations that fluctuate in size as environmental conditions change, even with the same mean and variance in environmental fluctuation, different temporal distributions of environmental conditions can lead to distinct biological adaptations associated with behavioral specialization or generalization. Thus, we provide a general framework for understanding the impacts of different temporal scales of environmental fluctuation on organisms with either overlapping or non-overlapping generational life histories. Future studies must move beyond viewing environmental variation as discrete classes of coarse-(among-generation) versus fine-grain (within-generation) and begin to investigate the existence of a potentially rich suite of adaptations to diverse environmental scenarios—those that vary in intensity, frequency, and duration—in an ever-changing world. Ultimately, our study not only helps bridge the apparent gap between theoretical and empirical studies of biological adaptation in a volatile world, but it also links under a synthesized theoretical framework seemingly distinct fields, such as macrophysiology32, species distribution modeling14,33, and social evolution10,18,34.
Methods
Discrete environment model (good and bad years, rising-tide and bet-hedging strategies)
The simplest way to capture this concept is to use two sets of competitive Lotka-Volterra equations (eqns. 1 and 2) with different equilibrium points. We constructed (i) an individual-based model with probabilistic algorithms to determine the upcoming environment and the birth and death events (i.e. a stochastic continuous time model with random environment setting, Fig. 1), and (ii) a deterministic model with traceable environmental change (i.e. deterministic continuous time model with periodical environment setting, Supplementary Fig. 1).
We use a dynamic time step (similar to Gillespie’s algorithm, see Supplementary Fig. 2) in the individual-based model, where S is the waiting time till next event, λ is the sum of all event rates of the differential equations (i.e. birth and death events, Supplementary Fig. 2), Y is a random number providing stochasticity to the waiting time, and c is a coefficient for adjusting the timescale. Whenever S is determined, a random event occurs according the rate of each events such that a new individual is born, or a living individual dies. As S deceases with increasing λ, this design flexibly changes the frequency of events based on the current population size.
How the environmental conditions are chosen is another crucial feature of these models. In the individual-based model, after one year has passed, the type of the next year is determined by the probability of good year through a random number draw. On the other hand, we assume good and bad years alternate in the deterministic model but the duration of each changes proportionally to the probability of good year (see supplementary information for more details of the deterministic model).
Continuous environment model (performance curve, bet-hedging generalist and rising-tide specialist)
To generalize our results and compare them to previous model15, we derived the continuous environment model (eqn. 3). Specifically, the carrying capacity of a strategy (i) follows a Beta function, where the shape parameters (s) determine the width and height of the performance curve, and the coefficients control the scale (cenv,K) or skewness (ccsk) of the curve. Further, Γ represents the gamma function, where Γ(n)=(n−1)!. Similarly, birth and death rate follow Beta functions with the same skewness (csk) and the same range of environmental conditions (cenv),
Because the skewness of the three parameters are equal, the mean of each beta function is the same (i.e. cenv(1/1+csk,i)). In other words, the only difference in the performance curves among all competitors is the shape parameter, making one strategy more like a bet-hedging generalist or a rising-tide specialist (Fig. 1a). Through this design, the competition in dynamics can respond to the various amounts of change in environmental conditions (e.g. changes in temperature or precipitation).
We have described how parameter values and the population dynamics of each strategy respond to various forms of environmental conditions. Next we determine how environmental conditions fluctuate through time. Since variation may occur in either the long-or short-term, we divide time into phases and episodes, where one phase consists of several episodes. In each time unit, the environmental conditions follow a symmetric Beta distribution, where the scaling coefficients define the range of environmental conditions, and the shape coefficients define the distributions and variation in environmental conditions. Hence, the current environmental conditions are the sum of two sampled values: one from the distribution of long-term variation (controlled by sphase), and another from the distribution of short-term variation (controlled by sepisode),
We validate the temporal scale of environmental fluctuations by the fast Fourier transformation (FFT), showing increasing long-term variation enhances the amplitude of low frequency components and increasing short-term variation enhances the amplitude of high frequency components (Supplementary Fig. 3).
Based on the continuous environmental settings, we derive two models using this framework: (i) a continuous; and (ii) a discrete population dynamics model. The continuous population dynamics model (i.e. a stochastic continuous time model with random continuous environmental settings) has the same demographic property as the deterministic environment models, where growth parameters (e.g. bs and ds) change instantly with the change of environmental conditions and the population dynamics follows eqns. 3a and 3b. On the other hand, suppose there are n episodes in one phase, the discrete population dynamics model (i.e. a stochastic discrete time model with random continuous environment setting) takes arithmetic mean from several parameters by the end of each phase, where i specifies the strategy and j denotes the index of episodes. Hence, the growth parameters are updated once per phase, and the population dynamic follows where t stands for the index of phases. Because of the process of taking averages, the meaning of short-term variation is no longer the smaller temporal scale of environmental changes. Instead, it expresses a finer type of variation (i.e. finer grain) that potentially deviates from the environment of each episode (Fig. 3).
Data Availability
All simulated data was generated using the C language. All code used for this study is available at https://github.com/mingpapilio/Codes_RisingTide.
Author Contribution
S.-F.S. conceived the idea. M.L., W.-C. L. and S.-F.S. constructed the models. M.L., D.D.R. and S.-F.S. designed the study, analyzed the data, and wrote the paper.
Acknowledgments
We thank Joshua B. Plotkin for the helpful comments for the earlier version of this paper. S.-F.S. was supported by Academia Sinica (Career Development Award and Investigator Award, AS-IA-106-L01) and Minister of Science and Technology of Taiwan (S.-F.S., 1002621-B-001-004-MY3, and 104-2311-B-001-028-MY3). D.R.R. was supported by the US National Science Foundation (IOS-1257530, IOS-1656098).