Skip to main content
Log in

Genetic versus phenotypic models of selection: can genetics be neglected in a long-term perspective?

  • Published:
Journal of Mathematical Biology Aims and scope Submit manuscript

Abstract

Game theoretical concepts in evolutionary biology have been criticized by populations geneticists, because they neglect such crucial aspects as the mating system or the mode of inheritance. In fact, the dynamics of natural selection does not necessarily lead to a fitness maximum or an ESS if genetic constraints are taken into account. Yet, it may be premature to conclude that game theoretical concepts do not have a dynamical justification. The new paradigm of long-term evolution postulates that genetic constraints, which may be dominant in a short-term perspective, will in the long run disappera in the face of the ongoing influx of mutations. Two basic results (see Hammerstein; this issue) seem to reconcile the dynamical approach of long-term population genetics with the static approach of evolutionary game theory: (1) only populations at local fitness optima (Nash strategies) can be long-term stable; and (2) in monomorphic populations, evolutionary stability is necessary and sufficient to ensure long-term dynamic stability. The present paper has a double purpose. On the one hand, it is demonstrated by fairly general arguments that the scope of the results mentioned above extends to non-linear frequency dependent selection, to multiple loci, and to quite general mating systems. On the other hand, some limitations of the theory of long-term evolution will also be stressed: (1) there is little hope for a game theoretical characterization of stability in polymorphic populations; (2) many interesting systems do not admit long-term stable equilibria; and (3) even if a long-term stable equilibrium exists, it is not at all clear whether and how it is attainable by a series of gene substition events.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this article

Price excludes VAT (USA)
Tax calculation will be finalised during checkout.

Instant access to the full article PDF.

Institutional subscriptions

Similar content being viewed by others

References

  • Akin, E. (1979): The Geometry of Population Genetics. Berlin: Springer-Verlag

    MATH  Google Scholar 

  • Allen, J. A. (1988): Frequency-dependent selection by predators. Phil. Trans. R. Soc. Lond. B319: 485–503

    Google Scholar 

  • Bomze, I. M. and B. M. Pötscher (1989): Game Theoretical Foundations of Evolutionary Stability. Lecture Notes in Economics and Mathematical Systems, Vol. 324. Berlin: Springer-Verlag

    MATH  Google Scholar 

  • Cavalli-Sforza, L. L. and Bodmer, W. F. (1971): The Genetics of Human Populations. San Francisco: W. H. Freeman

    Google Scholar 

  • Cressman, R. (1992): The Stability Concept of Evolutionary Game Theory. Berlin: Springer-Verlag

    MATH  Google Scholar 

  • Crow, J. F. and Kimura, M. (1970): An Introduction to Population Genetics Theory. New York: Harper & Row

    MATH  Google Scholar 

  • Eshel, I. (1982): Evolutionarily stable strategies and viability selection in Mendelian populations. Theor. Pop. Biol.22: 204–217

    Article  MATH  MathSciNet  Google Scholar 

  • Eshel, I. (1996): On the changing concept of population stability as a reflection of a changing problematics in the quantitative theory of evolution. J. Math. Biol.34: 485–510

    Article  MATH  Google Scholar 

  • Eshel, I. and Feldman, M. W. (1984): Initial increase of new mutants and some continuity properties of ESS in two-locus systems. Amer. Nat.124: 631–640

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Feldman, M. W. and Otto, S. P. (1991): A comparative approach to the population-genetics theory of segregation distortion. Amer. Nat.137: 443–456

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Hammerstein, P. (1996): Darwinian adaptation, population genetics and the streetcar theory of evolution. J. Math. Biol.34: 511–532

    Article  MATH  Google Scholar 

  • Hammerstein, P. and Selten, R. (1994): Game theory and evolutionary biology. In: R. J. Aumann and S. Hart (Eds), Handbook of Game Theory with Economic Applications, Vol. II. Amsterdam: Elsevier, pp. 929–993

    Google Scholar 

  • Hartl, D. L. and Clark, A. G. (1989): Principles of Population Genetics. Sunderland, Ms: Sinauer.

    Google Scholar 

  • Hofbauer, J. and Sigmund, K. (1988): The Theory of Evolution and Dynamical Systems. Cambridge: Cambridge Univ. Press

    MATH  Google Scholar 

  • Karlin, S. and Lessard, S. (1986): Theoretical Studies on Sex Ratio Evolution. Princeton, N. J.: Princeton, Univ. Press

    Google Scholar 

  • Lessard, S. (1984): Evolutionary dynamics in frequency-dependent two-phenotype models. Theor. Pop. Biol.25: 210–234

    Article  MATH  Google Scholar 

  • Lessard, S. (1990): Evolutionary stability: one concept, several meanings. Theor. Pop. Biol.37: 159–170

    Article  MATH  MathSciNet  Google Scholar 

  • Li, C. C. (1955): Population Genetics. Chicago: Univ. of Chicago Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Liberman, U. (1988): External stability and ESS: criteria for initial increase of new mutant allele. J. Math. Biol.26: 477–485

    MATH  MathSciNet  Google Scholar 

  • Matessi, C. and Di Pasquale, C. (1996): Long-term evolution of multilocus traits. J. Math. Biol.34: 613–653

    Article  MATH  Google Scholar 

  • May, R. M. (1985): Host-parasite associations: their population biology and population genetics. In: D. Rollinson and R. M. Anderson (eds): Ecology and Genetics of Host-Parasite Interactions. London: Academic Press, pp. 243–262

    Google Scholar 

  • Maynard Smith, J. (1982): Evolution and the Theory of Games. Cambridge: Cambridge Univ. Press

    MATH  Google Scholar 

  • Moran, P. A. P. (1964): On the nonexistence of adaptive topographies. Ann. Hum. Genet.27: 383–393

    Article  MATH  Google Scholar 

  • Parker, G. A. and Hammerstein, P. (1985): Game theory and animal behavior. In: P. J. Greenwood, P. H. Harvey and M. Slatkin (eds): Evolution. Essays in Honour of John Maynard Smith. Cambridge: Cambridge Univ. Press, pp. 73–94

    Google Scholar 

  • Parker, G. A. and Maynard Smith, J. (1990): Optimality theory in evolutionary biology. Nature,348: 27–33

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Partridge, L. (1988): The rare-male effect: what is its evolutionary significance? Phil. Trans. R. Soc. Lond. B319: 525–539

    Google Scholar 

  • Taylor, P. D. (1996): Inclusive fitness arguments in genetic models of behaviour. J. Math. Biol.34: 654–674

    Article  MATH  Google Scholar 

  • Turner, J. R. G. (1970): Changes in mean fitness under natural selection. In K. I. Kojima (ed.): Mathematical Topics in Population Genetics. Berlin: Springer-Verlag.

    Google Scholar 

  • Uyenoyama, M. K. (1988): On the evolution of genetic incompatibility systems. In: R. E. Michod and B. R. Levin (eds). The Evolution of Sex. An Examination of Current Ideas. Sunderland, Ms: Sinauer, pp. 212–232

    Google Scholar 

  • Weissing, F (1983): Populationsgenetische Grundlagen der Evolutionären Spieltheorie. Bielefeld: Materialien zur Mathematisierung der Einzelwissenschaften, 41 and 42.

    Google Scholar 

  • Weissing, F. (1991): Evolutionary stability and dynamic stability in a class of evolutionary normal form games. In: R. Selten (ed.): Game Equilibrium Models. I. Evolution and Game Dynamics. Berlin: Springer-Verlag, pp. 29–97.

    Google Scholar 

Download references

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Rights and permissions

Reprints and permissions

About this article

Cite this article

Weissing, F.J. Genetic versus phenotypic models of selection: can genetics be neglected in a long-term perspective?. J. Math. Biology 34, 533–555 (1996). https://doi.org/10.1007/BF02409749

Download citation

  • Received:

  • Revised:

  • Issue Date:

  • DOI: https://doi.org/10.1007/BF02409749

Key words

Navigation